3 - A Consumer's Constrained Choice Flashcards
How can we use information about consumers’ allocation of their budget across various goods in the past to predict how a price change will affect their demands for goods today? Are consumers better off receiving cash or a comparable amount in food stamps? Should people buy insurance or save their money? work at home or in the marketplace? Have children? Invest in bonds or in stocks? How do we answer such questions?
To answer these questions and other questions about how consumers allocate their income over many goods, we use a model that lets us look at an individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and market-determined prices.
What does the model we develop throughout this chapter allow us to do?
This model allows us to derive the market demand curve that we used in our supply-and-demand model and to make a variety of predictions about consumers’ responses to changes in prices and income.
Our model of consumer behavior is based on which premises? (3)
- Individual tastes or preferences determine the amount of pleasure people derive from the goods and services they consume.
- Consumers face constraints, or limits, on their choices.
- Consumers maximize their well-being or pleasure from consumption subject to the budget and other constraints they face.
How do consumers consume?
Consumers buy the goods that give them the most pleasure, subject tot he constraints that they cannot spend more money than they have nor can they spend it in ways forbidden by the government.
How do we summarize a consumer’s preference ranking for weak preference?
Using a preference relation ≥. If the consumer likes Bundle a at least as much as Bundle b, we say that the consumer weakly prefers a to b, which we write a≥b
How do we summarize a consumer’s preference ranking for strict preference?
If the consumer weakly prefers Bundle a to b, a≥b, but the consumer does not weakly prefer b to a, then we say that the consumer strictly prefers a to b, which we write a>b.
How do we summarize a consumer’s preference ranking for indifference?
If the consumer weakly prefers Bundle a to b and b to a, that is a≥b and b≥a, then we say that the consumer is indifferent between the bundles a and b, or likes the two bundles equally, which we write a~b.
What is the completeness property?
The completeness property holds that, when facing a choice between any two bundles of goods, Bundle a and b, a consumer can rank them so that one and only one of the following relationships is true: a≥b, b≥a or both relationships hold so that a~b
What does the completeness axiom rule out?
It rules out the possibility that the consumer cannot decide which bundle is preferable.
What is the transitivity property?
According to this property, a consumer’s preferences over bundles is consistent in the sense that, if the consumer weakly prefers a to b, a≥b, and weakly prefers b to c, b≥c, then the consumer also weakly prefers a to c, a≥c.
What is the preference relation ≥ said to be if the completeness and transitivity axioms hold?
Rational. That is, the consumer has well-defined preferences between any pair of alternatives.
What is the more is better property?
The more-is-better property states that, all else the same, more of a commodity is better than less of it.
How do economists regularly use the more-is-better principle it their language?
Economists define a good as a commodity for which more is preferred to less, at least at some levels of consumption. In contrast, a bad is something for which less is preferred to more, such as pollution.
What is one of the simplest ways to summarize information about a consumer’s preferences?
To create a preference map - a graphical interpretation - of them. For simplicity, we concentrate on choices between only two goods, but the model can be generalized to handle any number of goods.
What are indifference curves?
The set of all bundles of goods that a consumer views as being equally desirable.
What is a preference map?
A complete set of indifference curves that summarize a consumer’s tastes.
Why do we call preference maps “maps”?
Because it uses the same principle as a topographical or contour map, in which each line shows all points with the same height or elevation.
What does each indifference curve in an indifference map consists of?
Each indifference curve in an indifference map consists of bundles of goods that provide the same utility or well-being for a consumer, but the level of well-being differs from one curve to another.
Given our assumptions, all indifference curve maps must have which five important properties?
- Bundles on indifference curves farther from the origin are preferred to those on indifference curves closer to the origin.
- Every bundle lies on an indifference curve.
- Indifference curves cannot cross.
- Indifference curves slope downward.
- Indifference curves cannot be thick.
Why are bundles on indifference curves farther from the origin are preferred to those on indifference curves closer to the origin?
Because of the more-is-better property.
Why does every bundle lie on an indifference curve?
Because of the completeness property.
Why can’t two indifference curves cross?
Because preferences are transitive and consumers prefer more to less.
Why do indifference curves slope downward?
Because of the more-is-better property.
What is a utility function?
The relationship between utility measures and every possible bundle of goods.