Theory Flashcards
Spiritual Criminology
- early 18th century (middle ages)
- St. Thomas Aquinas (1225-1274)
- Aquinas said that a God-given “natural law” was revealed by observing, through the eyes of faith, people’s natural tendency to do good rather than evil
- criminal law based on this natural law
- Crime is a sin caused by evil spirits/devil
- Religious approach to understanding of crime
- Crime is a sin against God, King, and the ruling class
- crime was mostly a private affair where victims’ families took revenge on offenders’ family
- Punishment system based on private vengenance (ex: blood fueds, trials by battle, trials by ordeals (dunking, burning at stake)
- if you were evil, you deserved the punishment and punishment purified the soul
- religion was justification for punishment
- state utilized torture to punish sins on absolute moral authority of Natural Law
- Spiritual explanations of crime appeared in the “New World” in Puritan colony in MA (crime thought to have been caused by devil/witches)
- Quakers used this within punishment in 1790 by isolating offenders in cells with only a bible
Classical Criminology
- mid 18th century-mid 19th century
Rational choice approach to study of crime - Crime is anything prohibited by law
- Punishment system based on swift, certain, severe, proportionate penalties
- Colonial America built on this school
- Three strands of theory and research:
1. “rational choice perspective” (policy: focus on changing situations in order to influence people’s calculations)
2. deterrent effect of criminal justice policies
3. routine activities (policy: limiting criminal opportunities rather than increasing deterrent effect)
Hobbes
- 1588-1678
- “social contract thinkers”
- focused on naturalistic arguments
- argued that people naturally pursue their own interests
- people agree to give up selfish behavior as long as everyone else does the same (i.e., social contract”)
- state needs to act as enforcement mechanism for social contract
- everyone who agrees to social contract agrees to state being enforcement mechanism
Social Contract Thinkers
- Locke
- Montesquieu
- Voltaire
- Rousseau
- by mid 1700s (before Beccaria), naturalistic approach was well known and accpeted by intellectuals, but not by ruling groups
Beccaria Background
- Italian jurist, philosopher, politician
- mediocre, indifferent student from aristocratic family
- part of Young social movement
- “academy of fits”- literary society of Italian intelligentsia
- informal version of grad scool
- people who did not have to work got together to debate and thought they could change society by giving each other trasks to identity primary arguments against X or Y
- Beccaria was assigned to bullet point arguyments against “barbaric” system of justice
- anonymously published in Milan in 1764 when Beccaria was 26
- book served as guide for French code and US constitution
Philosophical Pillars of “On Crimes and Puinshment”
- human nature (voltaire): free will, hedonistic self-interest, rationally calculating
- fatalism v free will
- Utilitarianism (Betham/Mill): greatest pleasure to the greatest number
- Social contract (Hobbes/Locke): Secular view of formation of Law and Society:
1. Secular explanation of the formation of the political state; Mitigates purely utilitarian arguments
2. Utilitarianism works as a principle, only when it does not violate social contract
Principles of “On Crimes and Punishment”
- legislatures should define crimes and specific punishment for each crime
- judges should determine guilt and then follow law when sentencing (judges should not have any discretion)
- seriousness of crime is determined by harm to society (intent does not matter)
- purpose of punishment is to deter crime (punishment should be proportionate)
- punishments are unjust when severity exceeds deterrence
- excessive severity increases crime
- punishments should be swift
- punishments should be certain
- laws should be published and where everyone can understand them
- punishment should be based on the act not the person
Gibbs (1968)
- first empirical test of Beccari’s theory of deterrence
- defined certainty of punishment as ratio between number of admissions to state prisons for given crime to number of those crimes known to police in that year
- found greater certainty and severity of imprisonment associated with fewer homicides in 50 states in 1960s
- effect of certainty twice as great as effect of severity
Tittle (1969)
- examined effect of certainty and severity on seven index offenses in FBI UCR
- Found certainty associated with less crime for all 7
- more severity was associated with higher crime for all offenses except homicide
- Conclusions: certainty deters crime, but severity only deters crime when certainty is high
Chiricos & Waldo (1970)
- Tittle’s results could be explained by variations in police record keeping
- Some police may deal with certain crimes informally without making report, which would influence crime rates
Glaser & Zeigler (1974)
- argued against Gibb’s conclusion that increased imprisonment deters homicide
- showed that death penalty states have higher murder rates, but murderers in death penalty cases who are not executed serve shorter prison sentences than those in non-death penalty states
- argued that it is unlikely that longer prison sentences deter crime but death penalty does not
- attributed higher murder rates, use of death penalty, and shorter prison stays for murderers not executed to a lower valuation of human life in those states
Pratt & Turanovic (2018)’s thoughts on celerity
Celerity only matters if detection and response are immediate
Specific Deterrence
One’s punishment for a prior wrongdoing deters them from committing future offenses (Andenaes, 1974)
General Deterrence
relates to the threat of punishment; seeing other people be punished prevents a potential offender from offending.(Andenaes, 1974)
Matsueda et al. (2006): Deterring delinquents: A rational choice model of theft and violence
- analyze relationship between perceived certainty of arrest and delinquency
- found that perceptions of certainty of arrest were related to self-reported theft and violence
- those who perceived there were opportunities to commit theft and vioelnce and get away with it were more likley to report both acts
- anticipated gains and benefits of crime were influencial: those who perceived theft/violence as “exciting” or “cool” were more likely to report those acts
- relative effects of the costs and rewards of crime were roughly comparable in magnitude (even though costs would be delayed)
Piliavin et al. (1986): Crime, deterrence, and rational choice
- found evidence for reward component but not cost or deterrence component (as measured by percieved risks of formal sanctions)
Williams & Hawkins (1986): Perceptual research on general deterrence: A critical review
- reconceptualized general deterrence with an emphasis being on the idenfitication of the direct and indirect consequences of legal sanctions that promote deterrence
Stafford & Warr’s (1993) reconceptualization of deterrence
- Stated that general and specific deterrence should not be separated because they operate together and “people are likely to have a mixture of indirect and direct experience with punishment and punishment avoidance)
- Argue that general deterrence refers to indirect experience with punishment and punishment avoidance, whereas specific deterrence refers to direct experience with punishment and punishment avoidance
- Punishment avoidance suggests that potential offenders actively manipulate the risks of punishments by trying to avoid getting caught
Durlauf & Nagin (2011): Imprisonment and crime: Can both be reduced?
- Argued that both imprisonment and crime can be reduced if policymakers shift focus from severity-based policies (i.e., mandating length prison terms) to more effective use of police to make risks of crime clearer and punishment faster and more certain
Weisburd, Einat, & Kowlaski (2008): The miracle of the cells: An experimental study of interventions to increase payment of court-ordered financial obligations
- study of deterrence
- Project MUSTER
- deterrence based program, with threats of violation to court and incarceration and community service
- probationers sentenced to project MUSTER were significantly more likley to pay fines than TAU
- probationers who just had violation of probation had similar findings to MUSTER, indicating the threat of possible incarceration had a deterrence effect
Hawken & Kleiman (2009): Managing drug involved probationers with swift and certain sanctions: Evaluating Hawaii’s HOPE
- Deterrence based intervention
- Designed to reduce positive drug tests, arrests and imprisonment
- Administered short-but certain periods of lockup for failed drug tests and other probation violates
- Was not able to be replicated
Nagin’s 2013 review of deterrence four categories
- Four categories: imprisonment, policing, capital punishment, and perceptual deterrence
Nagin’s 2013 review of deterrence effect of imprisonment
- two methodologies: cross-sectional (i.e., are levels of imprisonment in different jurisdisctions causally associated with different levels of criminal behavior?) and longitudinal (do changes in imprisonment over time result in changes in criminal behavior?)
- evidence for deterrent effect
- imprisonment decreased failure to pay fines, success of Project HOPE, after three stikes law in CA, reduction of arrests for offenders with two previous strikes
Helland & Tabarrok (2007): Does Three Strikes Deter?
A Nonparametric Estimation
- compare post-sentencing activity of offenders convicted of strikeable offense to those tried for strikeable offense but convivcted of nonstrikeable offenses
- robustness check: comparison with states without three stike laws
- findings: CA’s three strike laws significantly reduces felony arrest tates among class of criminals with two strikes by 17-20%