5. Migrations Flashcards
Q: What is the split-stream model?
A stock grows in a given, common area and splits itself between economic zones of two (or more) countries. Each part of the stock remains in the zone to which it has migrated while it is fished, and then what is left in each zone migrates back to the growth area and grows and breeds as a unit.
Stock splits can either be:
a) Random or deterministic
b) Size-dependent
Q: Should each country get a share of TAC equal to the share of the stock in its zone (zonal attachment)?
This is not necessarily credible; a «small» player could be better off in a non-cooperative solution.
Question: What is the basis of the theory discussed in the text regarding fisheries management?
Answer: The theory is grounded in the economic and strategic aspects of fisheries management, particularly looking at situations where multiple countries with different interests and power levels are involved. It uses a game theoretical approach to understand this problem, focusing on the concepts of cooperative vs. non-cooperative strategies and their impact on fisheries management.
Question: What does the Zonal Attachment Principle imply, and when does it not work?
Answer: The Zonal Attachment Principle implies a connection between a country’s stake in the fisheries and its cooperation in management. However, it doesn’t always work due to potential inequalities, specifically when G(S°) is less than S+G(S).
Question: How is the critical value of 1-alpha calculated in the context of the Zonal Attachment Principle? What conclusion can be drawn from this?
Answer: The critical value of 1-alpha is calculated using a growth function as provided in the text. The conclusion drawn is that minor players often need to be offered a larger share of cooperative profits than corresponds to their share of the stock.
Question: How does cost sensitivity relate to resource exploitation?
Answer: When the cost per unit of fish caught is sensitive to the size of the stock, a minor player would leave some fish in his zone. It would not be profitable to catch all due to high costs.
Question: What has been the progress of fisheries management since the 200-mile zone establishment?
Answer: There has been progress in fisheries management, especially in economically advanced countries. However, many developing countries still face deteriorating fish stocks.
Question: What does the text suggest about rights-based management regimes?
Answer: The text mentions a study suggesting that rights-based management regimes, which involve individual transferable quotas, have been successful. The total limit on the catch and its effective enforcement is crucial for the biological status of fish stocks.
Question: How does international cooperation play out in the context of fisheries management, according to the text?
Answer: The text provides examples focusing on mackerel, herring, and blue whiting in the Northeast Atlantic. It discusses the negotiation of catch limits, the impact of negotiations failing to produce all-inclusive agreements, and the concept of uncoordinated fishing.
Question: What happens when formal agreements are not signed between countries involved in fisheries management?
Answer: The text proposes that countries often cooperate informally when formal agreements aren’t signed. These unilateral decisions don’t necessarily lead to harmful outcomes or stock depletion.
Question: What happens when countries engage in uncoordinated fishing, and how does this impact dominant and minor players?
Answer: When countries engage in uncoordinated fishing, this typically results in severe depletion of stocks. This effect is particularly notable when the cost per unit of fish is insensitive to the stock size, and the dominant country has a share close to or below a half.
Question: In the context of international fisheries management, what is meant by the term ‘rights-based management’?
Answer: Rights-based management refers to management regimes that include individual transferable quotas. This type of management has been found to be the most successful in improving fisheries management, and its continued introduction is deemed the most promising avenue to further improvement.
Question: What are some characteristics of the fisheries of mackerel, herring, and blue whiting in the Northeast Atlantic?
Answer: These species migrate extensively, passing through the exclusive economic zones of various entities. Each year, catch quotas and their distribution are negotiated for these species. When these negotiations do not result in an agreement signed by all, the countries involved often cooperate informally.
Question: What evidence is there that countries involved in fisheries management cooperate informally when formal agreements are not reached?
Answer: When negotiations on catch quotas do not result in a formal agreement, there is no apparent tendency for stock levels to fall in subsequent years. In fact, statistical analysis indicates that fishing mortality tends to increase in years with formal agreements in place, suggesting that countries are still cooperating informally when no formal agreement is reached.
Question: How does the cost per unit of fish caught relate to the size of the stock?
Answer: There is evidence that the cost per unit of fish caught is not very sensitive to the size of the stock. As long as any shoals remain, there will be enough to fill up a boat. This implies that the cost per unit of fish caught doesn’t increase significantly even when the stock size decreases.
Question: What happened to the Norwegian spring-spawning herring around 1970, and what lesson was learned from this?
Answer: The Norwegian spring-spawning herring suffered a collapse around 1970. This event served as a stark reminder of the consequences of overfishing, and it’s a lesson that the countries involved in fisheries management do not seem eager to repeat.
Question: How have the advances in fisheries management been since the establishment of the 200-mile zone?
Answer: There have been improvements in the state of world fisheries, especially in economically advanced countries. The average biomass for assessed stocks has increased since the beginning of the century and was higher than the maximum sustainable yield in 2016. However, in many developing countries, the status of fish stocks continues to deteriorate.
Question: What is the zonal attachment principle in the context of fisheries economics?
Answer: The zonal attachment principle refers to a country’s proportionate stake in fish stock based on the amount of that stock present in its exclusive economic zone.
Question: Why doesn’t the zonal attachment principle always ensure cooperative behavior among countries?
Answer: The principle may not work if the growth function of a country’s stock, G(S°), is less than the sum of a fixed stock, S, and its growth function, G(S). This means that a country may have less incentive to cooperate if it sees potential for greater benefit from its individual growth.
Question: How does cost sensitivity influence the exploitation of fish stocks?
Answer: When the cost per unit of fish is sensitive to the size of the stock, a country, especially a minor player, may leave some fish in their zone uncaught. This is because it wouldn’t be profitable to catch all fish due to increasing costs per unit.
Question: What has been the impact of the establishment of the 200-mile zone on world fisheries?
Answer: The establishment of the 200-mile zone has led to advances in fisheries management, with the average biomass for assessed stocks increasing since its establishment. However, improvements have been mainly seen in economically advanced countries, while fish stocks in many developing countries continue to deteriorate.
Question: What is rights-based management and why is it seen as successful?
Answer: Rights-based management refers to a management strategy involving individual transferable quotas. It’s considered successful because it provides a balance between economic efficiency and sustainable fishing practices by enforcing a limit on the total catch.
Question: How do negotiations around catch quotas work in an international setting and what happens when they fail?
Answer: In an international setting, catch quotas and their distribution are negotiated annually. When these negotiations fail to reach a formal agreement, countries often resort to informal cooperation and unilateral decision-making. Surprisingly, this doesn’t necessarily lead to harmful outcomes or severe stock depletion.
Question: What does the text imply about the relationship between the cost per unit of fish caught and the size of the fish stock?
Answer: The text suggests that the cost per unit of fish caught is not very sensitive to the size of the stock. In other words, even if the size of the fish stock decreases, the cost to catch each fish does not significantly increase.