TK7 Policy Instruments for Pollution Control (III) Flashcards
(18 cards)
Tradable Permits (Cap and Trade)
- Regulator issues emission permits (allowances).
- Each permit entitles one unit of pollution emissions (ex. 1 ton of
CO2). - Number of all permits in the economy = ‘cap’
- Each firm obtains an initial allocation of tradable permit though
grandfathering or auctioning. - Each firm’s initial allocation adds up to the aggregate ‘cap’.
Permit Market
- Permits are tradable in a permit market.
- If a firm wants to emit more than its initial allocation, buy permits in the
market. - If a firm chooses to emit less than its initial allocation, can sell permits in
the market
Tradable Permits – Important Observations
- The regulator can achieve the aggregate emissions target with certainty, assuming full compliance.
- A competitive permit market achieves the target cost-effectively.
- The regulator doesn’t need to know firms’ marginal abatement cost (MAC) curves for cost-effective allocation.
- Cost-effective allocation is independent of the initial permit distribution (per Coase Theorem).
- Initial permit allocation represents a valuable asset for firms.
Liabillity Defined
The regulator makes potential polluters responsible for any consequences but does not dictate actions, incentivising them to internalise risks and take socially optimal precautions
Liabillity Example
hazardous waste storage facility, offshore oil drilling rig
Liabillity Graph
effect of Liability
- The potential polluter wants to minimise the total social costs
because of liability - Liability makes the society’s objective agree with the polluter’s objective. That is, external costs are internalised
- Total social costs: TD(x) + TC(x)
- TD(x) is Total expected damages
- (x) is precaution
- TC(x) is total cost of production
Price-based regulations
- tax on emissions (or subsidy on abatement)
quantity-based regulations
- cap and trade
Price vs Quantity under certainty
- Price- and quantity-based regulations yield the same abatement levels if MAC and MB curves are certain
- both individual and aggregate
Price vs Quantity under certainty
- Price- and quantity-based regulations differ when uncertainty exists on the location of the MAC
curve.
Proposition (Weitzman) marginal benefits are more steeply curved
- quantity regulations are preferred if marginal benefits are more steeply sloped than marginal abatement costs
Proposition (Weitzman) marginal abatement cost curve is steep
- if the marginal abatement cost curve is steep then a price instrument like an emission tax is preferable
When should a quantity-based or price-based instrument be preferred in environmental policy under uncertainty?
- A steep marginal benefit curve implies a threshold effect, meaning small changes in emissions cause large changes in damage.
- For health-related regulations (e.g. local air pollutants), a quantity-based approach (e.g. cap-and-trade) is preferred.
- For global pollutants like carbon emissions, where marginal damages are smoother, a price-based approach (e.g. emission tax) is preferred for social efficiency.
Advantages of Economic Incentives over
Command and Control
- The equi-marginal principle automatically holds through
polluters’ individual decisions. As a result, the overall environmental goal is achieved at the lowest possible total cost to society - Information requirements are less significant.
- Provide an incentive for a polluter to innovate and/or find cheaper
ways of controlling pollution.
Disadvantages of Economic Incentives over
Command and Control
- Difficult to design economic incentives that can accommodate the
complexities of environmental transformation without being too
complex and impractical. - Ex. Urban air pollution: damage from a unit of emissions can vary in both
space and time. - On emission taxes: it is politically difficult to introduce an emission
tax as it involves massive transfers from polluters to the regulator. - Cap and trade may be able to avoid this difficulty as permits can be
initially given away freely to the polluter.
Pollution hot spots
- Pollution hot spots occur when the uniform mixing assumption fails, meaning pollutants do not disperse evenly.
- In such cases, emissions cause more harm in some locations than others.
- Simple emission taxes or cap-and-trade systems can lead to hot spots.
- This happens when firms in high-damage areas also face high abatement costs and opt to pollute more
how to address Pollution hot spots
- Using command-and-control regulations that directly restrict emissions in vulnerable areas.
- Adjusting market-based tools by setting location-specific tax rates, differentiated permit prices, or applying trade ratios that make it more expensive for firms in sensitive regions to emit.