TK7 Policy Instruments for Pollution Control (III) Flashcards

(18 cards)

1
Q

Tradable Permits (Cap and Trade)

A
  • Regulator issues emission permits (allowances).
  • Each permit entitles one unit of pollution emissions (ex. 1 ton of
    CO2).
  • Number of all permits in the economy = ‘cap’
  • Each firm obtains an initial allocation of tradable permit though
    grandfathering or auctioning.
  • Each firm’s initial allocation adds up to the aggregate ‘cap’.
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
2
Q

Permit Market

A
  • Permits are tradable in a permit market.
  • If a firm wants to emit more than its initial allocation, buy permits in the
    market.
  • If a firm chooses to emit less than its initial allocation, can sell permits in
    the market
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
3
Q

Tradable Permits – Important Observations

A
  • The regulator can achieve the aggregate emissions target with certainty, assuming full compliance.
  • A competitive permit market achieves the target cost-effectively.
  • The regulator doesn’t need to know firms’ marginal abatement cost (MAC) curves for cost-effective allocation.
  • Cost-effective allocation is independent of the initial permit distribution (per Coase Theorem).
  • Initial permit allocation represents a valuable asset for firms.
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
4
Q

Liabillity Defined

A

The regulator makes potential polluters responsible for any consequences but does not dictate actions, incentivising them to internalise risks and take socially optimal precautions

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
5
Q

Liabillity Example

A

hazardous waste storage facility, offshore oil drilling rig

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
6
Q

Liabillity Graph

A
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
7
Q

effect of Liability

A
  • The potential polluter wants to minimise the total social costs
    because of liability
  • Liability makes the society’s objective agree with the polluter’s objective. That is, external costs are internalised
  • Total social costs: TD(x) + TC(x)
  • TD(x) is Total expected damages
  • (x) is precaution
  • TC(x) is total cost of production
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
8
Q

Price-based regulations

A
  • tax on emissions (or subsidy on abatement)
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
9
Q

quantity-based regulations

A
  • cap and trade
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
10
Q

Price vs Quantity under certainty

A
  • Price- and quantity-based regulations yield the same abatement levels if MAC and MB curves are certain
  • both individual and aggregate
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
11
Q

Price vs Quantity under certainty

A
  • Price- and quantity-based regulations differ when uncertainty exists on the location of the MAC
    curve.
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
12
Q

Proposition (Weitzman) marginal benefits are more steeply curved

A
  • quantity regulations are preferred if marginal benefits are more steeply sloped than marginal abatement costs
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
13
Q

Proposition (Weitzman) marginal abatement cost curve is steep

A
  • if the marginal abatement cost curve is steep then a price instrument like an emission tax is preferable
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
14
Q

When should a quantity-based or price-based instrument be preferred in environmental policy under uncertainty?

A
  • A steep marginal benefit curve implies a threshold effect, meaning small changes in emissions cause large changes in damage.
  • For health-related regulations (e.g. local air pollutants), a quantity-based approach (e.g. cap-and-trade) is preferred.
  • For global pollutants like carbon emissions, where marginal damages are smoother, a price-based approach (e.g. emission tax) is preferred for social efficiency.
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
15
Q

Advantages of Economic Incentives over
Command and Control

A
  • The equi-marginal principle automatically holds through
    polluters’ individual decisions. As a result, the overall environmental goal is achieved at the lowest possible total cost to society
  • Information requirements are less significant.
  • Provide an incentive for a polluter to innovate and/or find cheaper
    ways of controlling pollution.
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
16
Q

Disadvantages of Economic Incentives over
Command and Control

A
  • Difficult to design economic incentives that can accommodate the
    complexities of environmental transformation without being too
    complex and impractical.
  • Ex. Urban air pollution: damage from a unit of emissions can vary in both
    space and time.
  • On emission taxes: it is politically difficult to introduce an emission
    tax as it involves massive transfers from polluters to the regulator.
  • Cap and trade may be able to avoid this difficulty as permits can be
    initially given away freely to the polluter.
17
Q

Pollution hot spots

A
  • Pollution hot spots occur when the uniform mixing assumption fails, meaning pollutants do not disperse evenly.
  • In such cases, emissions cause more harm in some locations than others.
  • Simple emission taxes or cap-and-trade systems can lead to hot spots.
  • This happens when firms in high-damage areas also face high abatement costs and opt to pollute more
18
Q

how to address Pollution hot spots

A
  • Using command-and-control regulations that directly restrict emissions in vulnerable areas.
  • Adjusting market-based tools by setting location-specific tax rates, differentiated permit prices, or applying trade ratios that make it more expensive for firms in sensitive regions to emit.