Chapter 6: Credit Rationing & Information Problems Flashcards
(6 cards)
What is credit rationing?
When banks refuse to lend to some borrowers—even those willing to pay high rates—because raising rates further would worsen their expected return by attracting only the riskiest applicants.
Why can the supply of credit be backward‐bending?
As the interest rate rises, safer borrowers drop out, leaving a riskier pool; beyond a certain point, higher rates reduce expected repayments, so banks cut back lending instead of raising rates.
In the Stiglitz–Weiss adverse‐selection model, why does raising rates eventually lower expected returns?
Higher rates drive out low‐risk firms, so the remaining borrowers are riskier and less likely to repay—making the bank’s average yield fall beyond a certain rate.
What surprising result emerges from the de Meza–Webb model?
Under some parameter values, banks may overlend, funding projects whose social return is below cost, because entry forces rates so low that average success probability exceeds the break-even threshold.
How does costly monitoring generate credit rationing?
Auditing each loan costs money; as rates rise, more borrowers default or trigger audits, driving up monitoring costs and eventually reducing net expected repayments, which leads banks to limit lending.
What is the moral‐hazard channel of credit rationing?
At higher rates, borrowers switch from safe to risky projects because they keep the upside; this shift lowers the probability of repayment, so banks cap loan volumes rather than push rates into the range that induces reckless borrowing.