Monetary Policy (Stabilisation Policy, Optimal MP, Interest Rate Rules (big)) (not technical, just equations to rmb) Flashcards

(30 cards)

1
Q

Over long run - what is the cause of high inflation

A

Excessive money creation

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
2
Q

Short run action for monetary policy makers

A

Want to know how policy makers should respond to various shocks

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
3
Q

Main macro model used:

A

COMPASS - a New Keynesian general equilibrium model

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
4
Q

Assumptions of COMPASS New Keynesian model

A) Prices and wages are sticky. What does this mean

B) role of expectations - they impact what? (2)

A

Prices and wages sticky, so MP affects output and employment in the short to medium term

Expectations also impact current output and inflation

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
5
Q

So we said how in the long run high inflation is caused by misguided MP; we can show this by

Quantity theory of money - expression

B) logged version

A

MV = PY

B)
Take logs of it to get
m+v = p+y (Lower case represents logged version)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
6
Q

Then add growth rates
βˆ†π‘š + βˆ†π‘£ = βˆ†π‘ + βˆ†π‘¦

Given V is stable. What do we get (final QToM eq)

A

πœ‹ = 𝜎 βˆ’ 𝑔

Inflation = money supply growth rate - GDP growth rate

I.e inflation is caused by money supply growing faster than GDP. Hence why Friedman’s k% rule to ensure 𝜎=𝑔 to have no inflation.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
7
Q

That was long run considerations. (Short, we focus on short run)

What do policymakers consider in the short run? (4)

A

Stabilisation policy and inflation targets

Optimal MP

Interest rates rules

Zero lower bound and liquidity traps

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
8
Q

Policymakers need to consider stabilisation policy:

Why does high inflation need stabilising (why is it costly for a) households and b) firms c) tax system

A

Households - waste time/resources economising on their holdings of cash; (banking time or shoe leather costs)

B) Firms waste time/resources trying to calculate price (menu costs)

C) Fiscal drag - more in higher tax bands if tax bands don’t rise with it

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
9
Q

What has happened to income tax in UK

A

Income tax threshold frozen until 2027/28

Bad for households, good for government (earn more tax revenue without actually rising taxes - a stealth tax!)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
10
Q

So those are 3 negatives to households, firms and tax system (but gov benefit from fiscal drag)

Benefits to inflation (2)

A

Grease wheels of labour markets - cut real wage cuts stealthily (keeping nominal wage constant while inflation rises)

Higher inflation target = higher interest rates = less likely to hit the ZLB nominal interest rates

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
11
Q

Conclusion on inflation - good or bad

A

Little bit of inflation might be healthy and useful, but too much is destabilising with costs to society.

(Healthy as shows people are buying stuff - zero inflation can mean 0 growth like Japan had 0 inflation because of 0 growth!)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
12
Q

So incentive to control inflation from being too high as destabilising. (3 reasons for households, firms, tax system)

What about stabilising output or unemployment?

Compare UK vs US stabilisation policy

A

UK inflation target

US dual mandate - equal weight on inflation and unemployment

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
13
Q

We can express this by
Central Bank loss function (a negative utility function, where we want to minimise losses) pg6

A

L = b(Ο€t - Ο€T)Β² + (yt - ye)Β²

Ο€t: actual inflation
Ο€T: inflation target
yt: acutal output
ye: long run output
b: how much CB cares about inflation relative to output

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
14
Q

Intuition of b:
b=1
b>1
b<1

B) pg6
Diagrams of loss function if b=1 b>1 b<1

A

b=1 dual mandate (equally weight inflation/output)
b>1 inflation target (weight inflation more)
b<1 output primacy (weight output more - less likely irl)

B) at bliss point L=0 no loss! Unrealistic tho
b>1 = inflation target looks squashed vertically
b<1 = output primacy looks squashed horizontally

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
15
Q

2nd consideration of policymakers: optimal MC
What does the central bank do to optimise their policy

A

Minimise their loss function

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
16
Q

What is the issue with minimising CB loss function

A

Optimal policy is sensitive to the model specification /misspecification

I.e if model is wrong, which it is often not perfect and mispeciffied, policy recommendations will be wrong

17
Q

Alternative to avoid this

A

Instead of loss function, add monetary policy rule to the model. E.g Taylor rule, Canonical NK model

This way it still works even if model incorrectly specified

18
Q

Canonical New Keynesian model 3 equations, what is the MP rule

B) General Intuition

A

Demand side NKIS
Supply side Phillips curve

MP rule:
it = πœ™πœ‹πΈπ‘‘πœ‹π‘‘+1 + πœ™π‘¦πΈπ‘‘π‘¦π‘‘+1 + πœ€π‘‘π‘€π‘ƒ

πœ™Ο€ responsiveness of CB with interest rates to inflation
πœ™y responsiveness of CB with interest rates to output

B)
Forward looking - If expected inflation EtΟ€t+1 increases, increase current interest rates now, as know it lags exist - takes time to get desired effects, hence raise now!

19
Q

3 equilibrium types in dynamic models

A

Unique and stable

Explosive

Multiple equilibria (sunspots)

20
Q

Unique and stable, what happens here (good)

And example

A

Economy returns to its long-run equilibrium following a shock

E,g with RBC we see shocks, and then come back to LR eq.

21
Q

Explosive equilibrium (not good)

A

Endogenous variables such as output and inflation, shoot off to + or - infinity following a shock, never come back to LR eq.

Policy tries to stop this from happening e.g stop hyperinflation

22
Q

Multiple equilibria (sunspots) equilbrium

B) example of this equilibrium

A

Multiple equilibria exist, some may be stable some not. Problematic since equilibrium is whatever agents expect it to be (self-fulfilling!)

B) DD model - 2 possible nash equilibrium:
Socially-optimal outcome: people follow their preferences (Type A withdraw and type B save - this is the stable equilibrium)

But if B believes all types withdraw, all withdraw as don’t wanna end up with nothing. Banks liquidate projects. This is the unstable equilibrium. (Self-fullfilling, not based on economic fundamentals!)

23
Q

Recall Taylor’s interest rate rule:

B) Under this, what equilibrium types we just looked at are possible, and under what conditions

C) why is it not realistic

A

It = πœ‹π‘‘ + p + πœƒπœ‹(πœ‹π‘‘βˆ’ πœ‹π‘‘*)+ πœƒπ‘Œ(π‘Œπ‘‘βˆ’π‘Œbar𝑑)

B)
unique and stable (if πœƒπœ‹>0)
or explosive (if not >0 get hyperinfaltion)

C) as this rule is not forward looking - IRL CB’s look ahead. With a forward looking rule equilibrium type 1 and 3 (multiple equilibria) are possible

24
Q

When we have a forward looking rule, which equilibrium types are possible.

A

Type 1 and 3
(Unique and stable, multi equilibria - expectations drive outcome i.e selfullfilling like DD model)

(Type 3 when πœ™πœ‹ < 1, type 1 when >1, PTO!)

25
So we use a forward looking (better than Taylor rule which doesn’t include forward looking): Like the previous (or Clarida, next one) it = πœ™πœ‹πΈπ‘‘πœ‹π‘‘+1 + πœ™π‘¦πΈπ‘‘π‘¦π‘‘+1 + πœ€π‘‘π‘€π‘ƒ Suppose that πœ™π‘¦ = 0 and πœ™πœ‹ > 1 Consider a rise in expected inflation: what do CB’s do?
CB increase it (nominal) by more than the rise in expected inflation, in order to increase the real interest rate!
26
So CB increase real interest rates via overshooting the nominal rate. Main implications - what is no longer possible now, and why? (Good thing)
Type 3 (multiple equilibria) no longer possible! No self-fulfilling expectations, as CB’s have a credible plan (overshoot nominal rates) if expected inflation gets out of control, and agents know this and believe it. Just the threat to raise interest following a rise in expected inflation prevents any increases in the first place. (Like in DD model, all they needed was a credible promise that government would back deposits (in order to prevent type B’s also withdrawing in panic)
27
Clarida rule (i*t) : pg 9 (another forward looking MP rule, slightly diff from the MP rule Canonical NK model one)
𝑖*𝑑= rn + πœ™πœ‹(𝐸𝑑[πœ‹π‘‘+π‘˜]βˆ’ Ο€*) + πœ™π‘¦πΈπ‘‘[lnπ‘Œπ‘‘+π‘˜βˆ’ lnπ‘Œ to the n 𝑑+π‘˜] K>0 since forward looking i*t: interest rate CB announces rn: natural/LR real interest rate Ο€*: inflation target πœ™πœ‹: responsiveness of interest rate to expected inflation, if it moves away from inflation target) πœ™y: responsiveness of interest rate to expected output inflation, if it moves away from long run output) i.e expected output gap
28
Clarida also adds interest rate smoothing. What is meant by this? B) interest rate smoothing expression
Policy makers dont want to scare and do all in one, they spread out changes over multiple policies B) 𝑖𝑑 = πœŒπ‘–π‘‘βˆ’β‚ + (1 βˆ’ 𝜌)𝑖𝑑* P measures degree of smoothing (0
29
Looked at empirics, A) prevolcker era has πœ™πœ‹= 0.83. Meaning: B) second period πœ™πœ‹= 2.15
πœ™πœ‹= 0.83. <1!!! Recall if πœ™πœ‹>1 means self fulfilling i.e multiple equilibria. Since <1, means we get type 3 equilibrium (pg9 or FC27) Second period: πœ™πœ‹ = 2.15, >1 so we get unique and stable!
30
So that was 3rd consideration of policymakers: interest rate rules. Now final short-run consideration: zero lower bound and liquidity traps. Interest rate controls seemed to work well, until GFC. Why?
Interest rates went to 0, but economy still in recession. Hard to lower below 0. So interest rates weren’t effective here.