Week 12 - Externalities and Public goods Flashcards

(68 cards)

1
Q

What is a negative externality?

A

A negative externality is a cost of an activity that falls on people other than those who pursue the activity.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
2
Q

What is a positive externality?

A

A positive externality is a benefit of an activity received by people other than those who pursue the activity.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
3
Q

Why do people tend to make decisions based on private costs and benefits?

A

People tend to make decisions based on the costs they actually incur and the benefits they actually receive (private costs/benefits).

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
4
Q

What happens when there is a positive externality in terms of decision-making?

A

An activity will be undertaken at a level less than what is socially optimal

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
5
Q

What happens when there is a negative externality in terms of decision-making?

A

An activity will be undertaken at a level greater than what is socially optimal.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
6
Q

In the COVID vaccine example, if the monetary benefit to a self-interested person is £100 and the additional benefit to society is also £100, but the cost of the vaccine is £150, will the person purchase the vaccine?

A

The person will not purchase the vaccine because their private benefit (£100) is less than the cost (£150), even though it would be socially optimal for them to get vaccinated, as the total social benefit exceeds the cost.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
7
Q

What is the result when a market has no external costs or benefits?

A

The resulting equilibrium quantity and price are socially optimal.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
8
Q

What do the private marginal cost (MC) and demand (also marginal benefit, MB) curves represent?

A

The private MC and demand curves represent the private costs and benefits in the market, without considering externalities.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
9
Q

What happens when there are no externalities in the market in terms of equilibrium?

A

The market reaches an equilibrium quantity and price where the private MC and demand (MB) curves intersect, and this outcome is socially optimal.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
10
Q

What happens when the production of a good has an external cost?

A

The market equilibrium price is too low, and the market equilibrium quantity is too high.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
11
Q

What is the equation for Social Marginal Cost (Social MC) when external costs (XC) are present?

A

Social MC = Private MC + XC, where XC represents the external cost per unit

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
12
Q

What is the socially optimal level of production in terms of marginal social benefit (MSB) and marginal social cost (MSC)?

A

The socially optimal level of a good occurs when the marginal social benefit (MSB) equals the marginal social cost (MSC).

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
13
Q

What is deadweight loss?

A

Deadweight loss is the loss of total surplus (consumer and producer surplus) that occurs when a market is not in equilibrium, typically due to externalities or market distortions like taxes or subsidies.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
14
Q

How does deadweight loss relate to externalities?

A

When externalities are present, the market produces either too much (in the case of negative externalities) or too little (in the case of positive externalities) of a good, leading to deadweight loss as the quantity produced is not socially optimal.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
15
Q

How is deadweight loss represented in a graph with externalities?

A

Deadweight loss is represented by the area between the supply curve (or private MC curve) and the demand curve (or MB curve) at the quantity produced in the market, where the socially optimal quantity is not being reached.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
16
Q

How does deadweight loss occur in the case of a negative externality?

A

In the presence of a negative externality (like pollution), the market produces more than the socially optimal quantity, causing an overproduction of the good and resulting in deadweight loss.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
17
Q

How does deadweight loss occur in the case of a positive externality?

A

In the presence of a positive externality (like vaccination), the market produces less than the socially optimal quantity, leading to underproduction and deadweight loss.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
18
Q

What is the socially optimal quantity in the context of externalities?

A

The socially optimal quantity is the level of output where marginal social benefit equals marginal social cost, maximising total welfare and eliminating deadweight loss.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
19
Q

What happens when externalities are present in a market?

A

The market outcome may be inefficient, resulting in either overproduction or underproduction of a good relative to the socially optimal level.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
20
Q

What is the equilibrium price and quantity when there are no externalities?

A

The market equilibrium quantity is Q_PVT, and the equilibrium price is P_PVT. This is the socially optimal outcome in the absence of external costs or benefits.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
21
Q

What is the relationship between the market equilibrium quantity and the socially optimal quantity when there are externalities?

A

When externalities are present, the market equilibrium quantity Q_PVT is smaller than the socially optimal quantity Q_SOC because individual buyers only account for the benefits they personally reap.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
22
Q

How is social demand different from private demand?

A

Social demand is the private demand plus the external benefit X_B (for positive externalities), reflecting the total benefit to society.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
23
Q

What condition should hold for the socially optimal level of a good?

A

The socially optimal level of a good should occur where the marginal social benefit (MSB) equals the marginal social cost (MSC).

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
24
Q

In a graph with externalities, how is the socially optimal quantity (QSOC) determined?

A

The socially optimal quantity Q_SOC is where the marginal social benefit curve intersects the marginal social cost curve, which considers both private and external costs/benefits.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
25
What is the Coase Theorem?
The Coase Theorem suggests that, under certain conditions, people can arrive at efficient solutions to the problems caused by externalities through bargaining, without government intervention.
26
1. In the example of Zoe (factory owner) and Ian (fisherman), what happens if Zoe dumps toxic waste into the river without a filter? 2. What happens if Zoe installs a filter to prevent the toxic waste from being dumped into the river? 3. In the case where Zoe and Ian can communicate, is there a way for both to benefit? 4. What happens if Zoe and Ian cannot communicate? 5. How can the problem of externalities be solved through the Coase Theorem in this example?
1. Zoe earns £130/day, and Ian earns £50/day, but Ian is negatively affected by the pollution. 2. Zoe earns £100/day (due to the cost of the filter), and Ian earns £100/day (since his fishing is no longer impacted by the pollution). 3. Yes, Ian can offer Zoe £40/day to install the filter. After this arrangement, Zoe earns £130/day and Ian earns £100/day, both benefiting from the agreement. 4. Zoe will not install the filter because the cost (£100/day) outweighs her benefit (£130/day). Ian, however, would want the filter installed, as it would increase his earnings from £50/day to £100/day. 5. If transaction costs are low, Ian can offer Zoe £40/day to install the filter. This would compensate Zoe for the cost and address Ian's concern, solving the externality problem.
27
What is the central idea of the Coase Theorem?
The Coase Theorem states that if contracting is possible at no cost (i.e., no transaction costs), people can always arrive at efficient solutions to the problems caused by externalities.
28
Who is Ronald Coase, and what is his contribution to economics?
Ronald Coase was a British economist who won the Nobel Prize in 1991 for his observation that efficient solutions to externalities can be achieved through bargaining when transaction costs are zero.
29
Under the Coase Theorem, what condition must hold for individuals to reach an efficient solution to externalities?
Contracting must be possible without any costs (i.e., no transaction costs), allowing parties to negotiate and internalise the externality.
30
How does the Coase Theorem differ from traditional government intervention in externalities?
The Coase Theorem suggests that private bargaining, without government intervention, can solve externalities efficiently, provided there are no transaction costs.
31
In the Coase Theorem, what role do property rights play?
Property rights determine who has the authority to allow or prevent externalities, and this shapes the direction of negotiation, but the efficient outcome can still be achieved if bargaining is costless.
32
1. In the example where Ian owns the river, what is Zoe’s default option? 2. Can Zoe and Ian still reach an efficient outcome if Zoe values not using the filter by more than £30/day and Ian values clean water by more than £30/day?
1. Zoe must install a filter unless Ian grants her permission to pollute the river. 2. Yes. Zoe could pay Ian (e.g., £40/day) to allow her to operate without a filter, compensating him for the pollution, achieving efficiency.
33
What is a key practical limitation of the Coase Theorem?
It assumes costless negotiations, which is rarely true in real life due to legal, informational, and coordination costs.
34
What can governments do when negotiation is costly or impractical?
They can use legal remedies such as taxes (e.g., carbon tax), subsidies (e.g., for vaccines), or regulations to align private incentives with social welfare.
35
What is the policy goal of taxes and subsidies in correcting externalities?
To internalise the externality—making private decision-makers bear the full social cost or benefit of their actions.
36
What is a private good?
A private good is both excludable and rivalrous—its use by one person reduces availability for others, and people can be prevented from using it.
37
What does excludability mean in economics?
Excludability means a person can be prevented from using a good, usually through pricing or ownership rights.
38
What does rivalry in consumption mean?
Rivalry means that one person’s use of a good reduces its availability for others.
39
Why is a mobile phone considered a private good?
It’s excludable (you can stop others from using it) and rivalrous (your use prevents others from using it at the same time).
40
What are the two properties used to classify types of goods in economics?
Excludability and Rivalry in consumption.
41
What are the four types of goods based on excludability and rivalry?
Private Goods – Rivalrous and Excludable Common Goods (Common Resources) – Rivalrous and Non-Excludable Club Goods (Collective Goods) – Non-Rivalrous and Excludable Public Goods – Non-Rivalrous and Non-Excludable
42
Give an example of a private good.
A sandwich, a mobile phone — rivalrous and excludable.
43
Give an example of a common good.
Fish in the ocean, public grazing land — rivalrous but non-excludable.
44
Give an example of a club good.
Netflix subscription, private parks — excludable but non-rivalrous (up to a point).
45
Give an example of a public good.
National defence, street lighting — non-rivalrous and non-excludable.
46
What are common goods in economics?
Goods that are rivalrous but non-excludable, meaning anyone can use them, but one person’s use reduces availability for others.
47
Give two examples of common goods.
Fish in the ocean and shared grazing land.
48
What is the Tragedy of the Commons?
The tendency for common goods to be overused or depleted, because individuals act in their own self-interest rather than the collective good.
49
Who first introduced the idea behind the Tragedy of the Commons?
William Forster Lloyd in 1833.
50
Who popularized the term "Tragedy of the Commons"?
Garrett Hardin in a 1968 article.
51
What key condition must exist for a Tragedy of the Commons to occur?
The resource must be open to all—non-excludable and subject to rivalrous use.
52
Why does overuse occur in the commons even if it leads to long-term depletion?
Because each person faces only their private cost, which is lower than the full social cost, leading to overconsumption.
52
In the Tragedy of the Commons, why is adding one more animal individually rational but socially harmful?
Because the marginal private benefit goes entirely to the individual, while the cost of overgrazing is shared among all users.
53
What happens when land reaches grazing capacity in a commons scenario?
Both the private benefit of more grazing and the social cost of overgrazing occur, but the user only considers their own benefit and a fraction of the cost.
54
What is the economic term for the benefit to the individual of adding one more cow?
Marginal Private Benefit (MPB).
55
What is the term for the full cost to society of adding one more cow in a shared grazing area?
Marginal Social Cost (MSC).
56
Why is the marginal private cost of adding another cow lower than the marginal social cost?
Because the negative effects of overgrazing are spread across all users, not just the individual making the decision.
57
What are public goods?
Goods that are non-excludable and non-rivalrous in consumption.
58
What does it mean for a good to be non-excludable?
Individuals cannot be prevented from using the good, even if they don’t pay for it.
59
What does it mean for a good to be non-rivalrous?
One person’s use of the good does not reduce its availability for others.
60
Give three examples of public goods.
National defence, basic scientific research, and flood control dams.
61
What is the free-rider problem?
When people benefit from a public good without contributing to its cost, it reduces the incentive for others to provide or maintain it.
62
Why might public goods be underprovided in a free market?
Because of non-excludability, individuals can free-ride, so there is less incentive for private provision.
63
What is free-riding in the context of public goods?
When individuals benefit from a good without paying, relying on others to bear the cost.
64
What happens if everyone free-rides on a public good?
The good is underprovided or not provided at all, leading to market failure.
65
Why does free-riding cause market failure?
Because private markets lack incentives to supply goods from which they can’t exclude non-payers.
66
Who often provides public goods due to the free-rider problem?
The public sector (government).
67
Can private firms ever profitably provide public goods?
Yes—if they find indirect revenue models, like advertising in broadcast TV or radio.