Week 23 - Aggregate Demand, Aggregate Supply, Inflation Pt2 Flashcards

(31 cards)

1
Q

How does increased military spending affect aggregate demand (AD)?

A

It increases AD, shifting the AD curve to the right.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
2
Q

What happens when output exceeds potential output (Y > Y*) due to increased AD?

A

An expansionary gap forms, leading to higher inflation (π increases).

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
3
Q

How does the short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve respond to rising inflation?

A

It shifts leftward to SRAS’, as firms raise prices in response to higher costs and demand.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
4
Q

What is the long-run outcome after the SRAS shifts in response to inflation?

A

The economy returns to long-run equilibrium at potential output (Y) but with a higher price level (π).

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
5
Q

How Did Inflation Get Started in the
1960s?

A
  • In 1959-63 inflation averaged about 1%
  • By 1970 inflation was 6%
  • Fiscal Policy
    – Increases in defense spending
  • 1962-65 = $70 billion
  • 1968 = $100 billion
  • Monetary Policy
    – The Fed did not try to offset the increase in
    government spending
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
6
Q

What is an inflation shock?

A

A sudden change in the normal behaviour of inflation, unrelated to the nation’s output gap.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
7
Q

What is a key characteristic of an inflation shock?

A

It occurs independently of changes in output or the output gap.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
8
Q

Give an example of a historical inflation shock.

A

The OPEC oil embargo of 1973.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
9
Q

Give an example of a historical deflationary (negative) inflation shock.

A

The drop in oil prices in 1986.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
10
Q

What is the immediate effect of an adverse inflation shock on SRAS?

A

SRAS shifts leftward to SRAS’, increasing inflation (π’) and reducing output (Y < Y*).

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
11
Q

What is the short-run equilibrium result of an adverse inflation shock?

A

The economy moves to point B: lower output (Y’) and higher inflation (π’) — this is stagflation.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
12
Q

What happens without policy intervention after an adverse inflation shock?

A

Inflation eventually falls, and the economy returns to long-run equilibrium at point A.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
13
Q

What is the effect of policy intervention in response to an inflation shock?

A

AD is shifted to AD’, restoring output to Y* but resulting in a permanently higher inflation rate (π*).

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
14
Q

What is an aggregate supply shock?

A

It can be either an inflation shock or a shock to potential output.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
15
Q

What is a common effect of adverse aggregate supply shocks?

A

They reduce output and increase inflation.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
16
Q

How do shocks to potential output affect the economy?

A

They shift long-run aggregate supply (LRAS), lowering the economy’s capacity to produce at full employment.

17
Q

What happens to potential output (Y*) in a shock to potential output?

A

Y* decreases, shifting the LRAS leftward to LRAS’.

18
Q

What initial condition does the shock create in the economy?

A

Y > new Y*, resulting in an expansionary gap.

19
Q

How does the short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) respond to this gap?

A

SRAS shifts leftward to SRAS’, increasing inflation (π rises).

20
Q

What is the new equilibrium outcome after the shock?

A

The economy reaches equilibrium at point B, with output at the new Y*’ and a higher inflation rate (π’).

21
Q

Is the decline in output from a potential output shock temporary or permanent?

A

Permanent — the economy adjusts to a lower potential output level.

22
Q

What is the initial equilibrium in the short run before anti-inflationary policy?

A

At point A, where Y = Y* and inflation is 10%.

23
Q

What action does the Fed take to reduce inflation?

A

It implements contractionary monetary policy, shifting AD to the left (to AD’).

24
Q

What is the short-run result of the Fed’s action?

A

The economy moves to point B: Y < Y*, creating a recessionary gap.

25
What happens in the long run after the policy-induced recessionary gap?
The economy self-corrects as SRAS adjusts, bringing output back to Y* and lowering inflation.
26
What is the short-run effect of an anti-inflationary monetary policy on the economy?
The economy moves to point B, where output (Y) is less than potential output (Y*) and a recessionary gap forms.
27
What happens to inflation in the short run after the policy?
Inflation falls to 3% as a result of the contractionary monetary policy.
28
What is the long-run adjustment following the policy?
SRAS shifts rightward to SRAS’, increasing output to Y* and reducing inflation to 3%.
29
What is the final long-run equilibrium outcome?
The economy reaches long-run equilibrium at Y* with lower inflation (3%) and lower prices.
30
What is the general equation for output (Y) in terms of various economic factors?
Y = [C + cT + I + G + NX - (a+b)r], where C is consumption, cT is taxes, I is investment, G is government spending, NX is net exports, and r is the interest rate.
31
How does the Fed’s policy reaction function (r = r + gπ) affect the equation for Y?
The Fed’s policy reaction modifies the interest rate (r) by adding a term based on inflation (π), so the new equation becomes: Y = [C + cT + I + G + NX - (a+b)(r+gπ)]