Costas (Maks) reset Flashcards
(56 cards)
Title: Katz & Murphy (1992)
Changes in Relative Wages, 1963-1987: Supply and Demand Factors
Motivation: Katz & Murphy (1992) - Changes in Relative Wages, 1963-1987: Supply and Demand Factors
US wage gaps between high and low skill workers exploded after the late-1970s. Are those gaps mainly due to a flood of college grads (supply) or to rising employer demand for skill (skill-biased technological change)?
Setting: Katz & Murphy (1992) - Changes in Relative Wages, 1963-1987: Supply and Demand Factors
United States, 1963-87. Annual March Current Population Survey files track wages and hours for the whole workforce
Supply-Only Test: Katz & Murphy (1992) - Changes in Relative Wages, 1963-1987: Supply and Demand Factors
Compute the dot-product of wage changes and quantity changes for every five-year window. If only supply moved, the product should be negative; a positive sign means demand must have shifted, as supply cant explain the shift (hapened in mid 80s)
Test Demand: Katz & Murphy (1992) - Changes in Relative Wages, 1963-1987: Supply and Demand Factors
Collapse labour into “high-skill” and “low-skill” productivity units using the constant elasticity substitution (CES) production function.
Estimate the substitution elasticity (how fast or how slow do high skill workers substitute low skill workers) and wage ratio, to get the backed out demand trend (interpreted as skill-biased tech change).
Decomposing Demand Shift: Katz & Murphy (1992) - Changes in Relative Wages, 1963-1987: Supply and Demand Factors
Build counterfactual indices to ask how much of the demand shift comes within-industry up-skilling, between-industry reallocation, or trade.
Robustness: Katz & Murphy (1992) - Changes in Relative Wages, 1963-1987: Supply and Demand Factors
CES results unchanged when adding union density, import penetration, or alternative industry splits; trade-only and sectoral reallocation stories explain at most a minor share of the overall demand shift.
Technology, and not trade flows, explain the extra skill demand
Results: Katz & Murphy (1992) - Changes in Relative Wages, 1963-1987: Supply and Demand Factors
After 1980, there is a tech-driven rise in demand for college-level skill, overrunning earlier supply booms and pushing the wage premium up again. Most of the extra demand appears within industries, consistent with technology-driven up-skilling (SBTC)
Title: Autor, Levy & Murnane (2003)
The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration
Motivation: Autor, Levy & Murnane (2003) - The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration
Since the 1970s, the “middle” of the U.S. job market has thinned out: office clerks and factory workers have become scarcer, while well-paid professional jobs have multiplied. This paper asks whether the spread of cheap computers is the reason.
Setting: Autor, Levy & Murnane (2003) - The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration
US population survey data from 1960-1998 are merged with occupation-level routine scores (from the Dictionary of Occupational Titles)
Model: Autor, Levy & Murnane (2003) - The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration
The production function consists of (routine + computers) and non-routine labour.
Routine labour and computers are perfect substitutes (price of routine labour = price of computers) because employers are profit maximising and rational (i.e. if computers are cheaper, no one will hire routine labour, and vice versa).
When computers get cheaper, workers get displaced and move from routine to non-routine tasks.
Empirics: Autor, Levy & Murnane (2003) - The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration
1) Regress the change in the share of routine tasks on the computer adoption rate to see whether more routine-intensive industries actually switched to computers faster, as per the predictions of the model.
2) Run the same specification separately for college and non-college workers to verify that job routiness is moving for all education levels.
3) Within-occupation tests confirm that tasks inside job titles re-balance as computers get widespread and sectors shed routine tasks.
Robustness: Autor, Levy & Murnane (2003) - The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration
Common computer-price shock applies to all sectors; placebo decades show no effect; identical patterns appear across industries, education groups and occupations
Results: Autor, Levy & Murnane (2003) - The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration
Routine-heavy industries adopt computers earlier, automate clerical/assembly work and expand analytic and interactive tasks — both between and within occupations. This task re-allocation explains the bulk of the post-1970 surge in demand for college-educated labour.
Title: Autor & Dorn (2013)
The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the US Labor Market
Motivation: Autor & Dorn (2013) - The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the US Labor Market
Since 1980 the U.S. job distribution has formed a U-shape: middle-wage clerical posts shrank, while both high-pay professional roles and low-pay service jobs grew. The paper asks whether cheap computers, by automating routine office and production work, pushed displaced workers into in-person services
Setting: Autor & Dorn (2013) - The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the US Labor Market
The authors follow millions of workers in every Census from 1950 to 2005 in the United States
Model: Autor & Dorn (2013) - The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the US Labor Market
2-sector model of production: goods & services. The goods sector combines (routine labour + computers) and abstract non-routine labour. The service sector only includes manual non-routine labour.
If computers get cheaper, firms substitute routine labour for computers, lowering the price of the inputs of production and making goods cheaper as well.
Seeing that goods are cheaper, consumers spend less money on goods and more on services (as goods and services are imperfect substitutes). This incentivises service-firms to hire the displaced routine labour to meet the rising demand.
As such, cheap computers displace routine labour toward manual non-routine labour and raise wages at the top (abstract labour).
Empirics: Autor & Dorn (2013) - The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the US Labor Market
1) Regress changes in employment in the service sector on routine intensity (RTI share) to see if routine-heavy commuting zones (with high RTI) were the fastest to adopt computers and displace routine labour into manual non-routine labour.
2) Within the same commuting zones, see whether the U-shaped polarization is steeper in intitially routine-intensive areas.
3) Regress changes in the share of college students on routine intensity (RTI share) to see if routine-heavy commuting zones attract more college students (abstract non-routine / high-skill workers).
Robustness: Autor & Dorn (2013) - The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the US Labor Market
Instrument the 1980 routine share with the 1950 mix to avoid mechanical bias; control for entity and time fixed effects; replace PC use with hardware-investment data and obtain similar results.
Results: Autor & Dorn (2013) - The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the US Labor Market
Routine-heavy labour markets adopted PCs earlier, then shed clerical and factory jobs while expanding low-skill, face-to-face services.
Within these markets wages stretched into a pronounced U-shape, with it being steepest in high-routine CZs.
The inflow of college-educated workers grew, signalling stronger demand for abstract, non-routine tasks.
Title: Goos et al. (2014)
Explaining Job Polarization: Routine-Biased Technological Change and Offshoring
Motivation: Goos et al. (2014) - Explaining Job Polarization: Routine-Biased Technological Change and Offshoring
Why have middle-wage jobs vanished while both well-paid professional and low-paid service jobs expanded (polarization)? Authors test whether automation of routine work and its offshoring abroad can jointly reproduce this polar shape. (Many industries, allows for offshoring, Europe rather than US & within or between industires)