Term 1 Lecture 4 Flashcards

(33 cards)

1
Q

Single output case of a firm’s production

A

Q < f(z), it’s feasible to produce q using if the production function satisfies this equation
- technically efficient when q = f(z), so the greatest possible output is being produced given the inputs

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
2
Q

General formulation of a firm’s output

A
  • extend concept to a more complex production scenario using a production plan, or a net output vector - y
  • inputs are negative and outputs are positive
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
3
Q

Transformation function:

A

Feasibility of a production plan represented by f(y) < 0
- for single output case, function becomes f(q,-z)
Q - f(z)
- f(y) = 0 is the transformation frontier, the boundary between feasible and infeasible production plans

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
4
Q

Properties of production:
- possibility of shutdown
- monotonicity

A
  1. 0 output is possible, so f(0) < 0
  2. In an efficient production process, increasing the output of one good requires reducing the output of another, same for inputs.
    - Df/Dzi >/ 0 for specific inputs
    - DF/dyi >/ 0
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
5
Q

MRT

A

Rate at which one net output can be transformed into another while keeping the firm on its transformation frontier
- tradeoff between different outputs and inputs while technical efficiency is maintained
- differentiate f(y) = 0 with respect to yi to get MRT

-((DF/Dyi)/(DF/Dyj))

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
6
Q

Marginal product, MPi

A

Rate at which any input can be transformed into output, equal to slope of the production function with respect to input
- Df/Dzi
- additional output produced from an incremental increase in input zi

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
7
Q

MRTS

A

Rate at which one input must be increased as another is decreased to maintain the same level of output
- slope of the isoquant

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
8
Q

Convexity of input requirement sets

A

Convexity implies the set of input combinations is well-behaved, so firms can flexibly combine different inputs to achieve the same output
- in terms of isoquants: Convexity means that isoquants are convex to the origin, leading to a decreasing MRTS as you move along the isoquant
- diminishing utility of subbing one input for another more and more

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
9
Q

Elasticity of substitution

A

Measures how easily one input can be subbed for another while maintaining same level output
- captures curvature of isoquants and indicates responsiveness of input choices to changes in economic incentives
- formula expresses how the ratio of inputs changes in response to changes in MRTS between them
Oij = -((Dln(zi/zj)/(Dln(MRTSij)))

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
10
Q

Homotheticity

A

If input vectors which produce the same level of output remain proportional when scaled
- if f(Za) = f(Zb), then f(kZa) = f(kZb)
- means isoquants at higher levels are scaled versions of isoquants at lower levels
- MRTS are constant along rays along the origin

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
11
Q

Homogeneity:

A

All homogenous functions are homothetic, but not vice versa
- homogenous of degree a if f(Kz) = K^a.f(z)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
12
Q

Returns to scale

A

DRS:
- scaling up inputs leads in a less than proportionate increase in output, Kf(z) > f(kz), for k>1
- implied by concavity
IRS:
- scaling up inputs leads to a more than proportionate increase in output, Kf(z) < f(Kz) for K > 1
- implied by concavity of production function
CRS:
- scaling up inputs leads to a proportionate increase in output, homogeneity of degree 1

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
13
Q

Perfect substitutes in production key properties:
- q = f(z1,z2) = G(az1 + bz2)
- MP, MRTS, isoquants, Oij, RS, homothetic

A
  • MPz1 = a… and MPz2 = b…, both CONSTANT
  • MRTS = a/b
  • isoquants are parallel straight lines
  • elasticity of substitution is infinite: perfect substitutability
  • CRS
  • homothetic
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
14
Q

Perfect complements production function
- q = f(z1,z2) = min(az1, bz2)

A

MP is only positive if that input is the bottleneck
- MPz1 = a, if az1 < bz2, otherwise 0
- MPz2 = b if az1 > bz2, otherwise 0
L shaped isoquants, where corner lies along the ray through the origin with slope a/b
- CRS, if both inputs are scaled up by the same proportion, output increases by same
- homoethetic

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
15
Q

Cobb-Douglas production function
- q = f(z1,z2) = Az1^a.z2^b

A
  • MPz1 = aq/z1
  • MPz2 = bq/z2
  • MRTS = MPz1/MPz2 = az2/bz1, diminishing MRTS -> convex input requirement sets
  • oij = 1, constant
  • homothetic as MRTS only depends on the ratio between z1 and z2
  • RS: IRS if a+b > 1, etc
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
16
Q

CES production function
- q = f(z1,z2) = [Az1^a + Bz2^b]^b

A
  • MP
  • MRTS = (A/B)(z1/z2)^a-1
  • o = 1/1-a
  • homothetic - MRTS only depends on z1/z2, so homothetic
  • IRS if ab > 1, etc
17
Q

How to know if production is not homothetic

A

MRTS is not constant along rays
Is not homogenous of degree 0 in income and prices

18
Q

Firm profit FOC and SOC, link to MRTS

A

MPi = wi/p
- where w is an input price
- second order condition ensures a concave production function
- taking the FOC for two inputs and eliminating p, we get:
(Df/Dzi)/(Df/Dzj) = wi/wj, so MRTS equals the price ratio

19
Q

Unconditional input demand and supply functions

A
  • solving profit maximisation problem for input demands can be written as D(p,w), decreasing in wi
  • putting these demands into the production function f(z) will give output as S(p,w), the firm’s supply function, increasing in p
  • both homogenous of degree 0, so only relative prices matter
20
Q

Comparative statics and monotonicity

A

ChangeP.Changeq - ChangeW.ChangeZ >/ 0
- so if p, output price increases, then output q must also increase or stay the same
- if an input price wi rises, while output price p remains constant, then demand for that input zi must fall.

21
Q

Profit function including supply and demand

A

pS(p,w) - w’D(p,w)
- homogenous of degree one
- increasing the price of output cannot decrease profit
- increasing the price of an input can not increase profit

22
Q

Hotellings lemma from profit function

A

Deriving the profit function with respect to output price gives the supply function

Derivative of profit with respect to input prices gives input demand function.

23
Q

Symmetry

A

Second derivatives of the profit function are symmetric

Impact of a price change of one input on another input’s demand Di must be identical to the impact of a price change in wi on demand for Dj

Impact of output price on input demand is equal and opposite to the impact of input price on output supply

24
Q

Generalised profit maximisation problem

A

Max r’y subject to F(y) < 0
- r is the price vector of net outputs
- y is the net output vector
- F(y) represents technological constraints on production
- homogenous of degree 1
- differentiating with respect to price gives the supply rule
Dpi/dri = yi, positive if firm is a seller

25
Cost minimisation problem
Min w’z subject to q \< f(z) - given an output level q, firms choose inputs z to minimise costs - cost minimisation is a necessary condition for profit maximisation After taking FOC, MRTSij = wi/wj
26
Conditional input demands
H(q,w) represent input quantities which minimise cost for a given output level q and input prices w - differs from unconditional input demand as here, q is fixed - homogeneity of degree 0 - monotonicity: changeW.changeZ \< 0, so if one input price increases, then demand for that input must decrease
27
Cost function
Minimum cost required to produce a given level of output q using the optimal combination of inputs - C(q,w) = w’H(q,w), where w is the vector of input prices - cost function is increasing in input prices - homogeneity of degree 1
28
Shephard’s Lemma linking cost function and input demand
DC/Dwi = Hi(q,w) - partial derivative of the cost function with respect to an input price wi equals the conditional input demand - symmetry, the way input demand Hi responds to the price of another input wj is symmetric.
29
Relationship between conditional and unconditional input demands:
D(p,w) = H(S(p,w),w) - unconditional input demand is derived from the conditional input demand at the firm’s profit maximising supply - input price changes affect demand through two channels, direct substitution effects from cost min and indirect output adjustments from profit max
30
Responsiveness of input demands to changes in output
If technology is homothetic, then input choices scale proportionally with output - implies cost shares of different inputs remain constant.
31
Returns to scale and cost functions
CRS: - homogenous and homothetic, so cost function is proportional to output - C(q,w) = qk(w) DRS: - impossible to scale production plans up and multiplying output by k>1 will multiply costs by more than k IRS: - possible to scale production plans up multiplying output by k>1 will multiply costs by less than k
32
Relation between marginal and average costs:
MC>AC, AC is rising MC=AC, AC is at a stationary point, usually the MES
33
Profit maximisation model: Pq - C(q,w)
- FOC: P = MC - SOC: second derivative is greater than 0 - since shutdown is assumed possible, firms cannot make negative profits, P >/ C/Q - therefore firm’s supply curve is the portion of the MC curve which lies above the AC curve, ensuring non-negative profits.