Term 2 Lecture 10 Flashcards
(27 cards)
Summary
- once market reaches equilibrium, no way to make everyone better off through trade
- if individual demands are interdependent, like with public goods/ externalities, then efficiency can be promoted by public intervention
Walraian equilibrium in exchange economies have the general property of being
Pareto efficient
- no feasible allocation that all consumers are better off
Proof of Pareto efficiency in Walrasian Equilibrium
- known as the first fundamental theorem of welfare economics
Proof by contradiction:
- allocation r1, r2, such that r1 preferred to current q1, etc
- means these bundles could not have been affordable to equilibrium prices p, by WARP
- SUM(pirih) >/ SUM(piqih) = SUM(piwih), with at least one of these inequalities being strict, as at least one consumer strictly better off
- this would mean total cost of the new allocation is greater than the total income available - impossible.
The locus of Pareto efficient allocations is known as
The contract curve and is illustrated for a two good economy using the Edgeworth-Bowley box
- those allocations on the contract curve that are Pareto superior to the initial endowment allocation are known as the CORE
The core
- a subset of the contract curve which is better than the initial endowments
- if an allocation is in the core, it means both parties would voluntarily trade to reach it instead of staying with original endowments
- core represents fairer or more mutually beneficial trades that improve utility
Why may some Pareto-efficient outcomes be more socially desirable than others
Even if all outcomes on the contract curve are efficient, some may be unequal or unfair, depending on how resources were distributed initially - questions on distributional equity.
Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics
Says any Pareto-efficient allocation can be achieved as a competitive equilibrium, but only if we start with the right initial endowments
- means in theory, society could choose which PE outcome it wants and then redistribute initial resources, through taxes, once this is done, market can reach desired outcome efficiently through trade
What assumption does the second theorem depend on?
On convex preferences, essentially means consumers prefer balanced, diversified bundles of goods, rather than extreme allocations
How to determine PE allocations in an exchange economy?
- setup
- total resources (endowment) in the economy is denoted as k = SUM(wh), so total amount of goods available is the sum off what each household initially owns
- assume we are maxing the utility of one consumer, while ensuring the others received a specified level of utility u^h, for h = 2,3,4…
- quantity of goods left for household 1 is what remains after all others take their share, q1 = K - SUM(qh)
How to determine PE allocation in exchange economy
- optimisation problem
Max u1(K - SUM(qh)), s.t. Uh(qh) = u^h
- want to max the utility of household 1
- restricted by the fact that all other households must receive at least their required utility u^h
How to determine PE allocation in an exchange economy
- first order conditions
Du1/Dqi1 = (lamdaH)(DuH/DqiH), H = 2,3…
- implies:
((DuH/DqiH)/(DuH/DqjH)) = ((DuG/DqiG)/(DuG/DqjG))
- ensures all households have the same MRS between any too goods
- this is the condition for Pareto efficiency, means at optimal allocation, no one can be made better off without making someone worse off
Competitive markets naturally lead to PE allocations as they
force consumers to adjust their consumption so that all individuals’ MRS values match the common price ratio
- so no further trade can improve efficiency
Fundamental Welfare Theorems for Equilibria with Production:
The previous 2 theorems still hold in the presence of production as long as certain assumptions are extended
- suppose a competitive equilibrium allocation is not PE, so production plans x1, x2 and alternative allocation r1, r2 that is Pareto superior
- SUM(pirih) >/ SUM(piwih) + SUM(thetahk).SUM(piyik), where theta is ownerships of shares of firms by consumer h, sums to 1
- SUM(pi).SUM(rih) > SUM(pi).(SUM(wih) + SUM(yik))
Feasibility Conditon: SUM(rih) = SUM(wih) + SUM(xik)
- sub into 2 lines above, you get that the equilibrium production plants max profits because it suggests that the alternative production plan produces a strictly greater total value, which means equilibrium firms aren’t profit maximising, which contradicts the definition of comp eq.
Explanation of Efficiency of Equilibria with Production
- problem setup
- consumption allocation and production plans are chosen to maximise the utility of one consumer, e.g. h = 1
- utilities of other consumers are fixed at u^h
- technical feasibility constraints: I^K(Qk,-Lk) = 0, as if the form is operating efficiently on its PPF, function evaluates to 0
Explanation of Efficiency of Equilibria with Production
- the Pareto efficiency problem
Ensure: other consumers maintain utility u^h and production remains technically feasible
MAX u ( SUM(yk) - SUM(qh)), h = 2,3,…H
S.t. Uh(qh) = u^h and I^k(yk) = 0, where yk = (Qk, -Lk)
Explanation of Efficiency of Equilibria with Production
- FOC conditions for efficiency
Du1/Dqi = (lambda)Duh/Dqih = u^k.(Dtk/Dyk)
- lambda is the Lagrange multiplier for the consumer utility constraints
- u^k is the Lagrange multiplier for the firm’s production feasibility constraint
- FOC conditions show that marginal utility of consumption is aligned across consumers, and the MB of output equals the MC in terms of production constraints.
Equating MRS and MRT from FOC
(Duh/Dqih)/(Duh/Dqjh) = (DTk/Dyik)/(DTk/Dykj)
- LHS is the MRS, which measures consumer tradeoff between goods i and j
- RHS is the MRT, describing how firms convert inputs into different outputs
- in a competitive equilibrium, firms and consumers face the same price ratios, so MRS = MRT automatically.
Public goods are
Non-rivalrous and Non-excludable
Mathematical model for Public Goods
- one private good, denoted as qh, consumed individually by each person h
- one public good, denoted as Q, which is consumed collectively
Uh = uh( qh ,Q )
Tradeoff between private and public goods:
Economy has fixed total resource M
M = SUM(qh) + PQ
- P is the cost in private goods to produce one unit of the public good
Efficient supply of public goods
- problem
Max u1( M - SUM(qh - PQ,Q)), s.t. Uh(qh,Q) = u^h
Efficient supply of public goods
- FOC
Private good allocation condition: MU of consumption for consumer 1 should equal that of other consumers
- Du1/Dq1 = (lambda^h).Duh/Dqh
Public good allocation condition: MC of providing P should equal the sum of all the individuals’ MB
- P.(Du1/Dq1) = Du1/DQ + SUM(lambda^h).(Duh/DQ)
Samuelson condition
Efficient provision of a public good requires that the sum of individual MRS equals the MC of providing the Public Good
P = SUM((Duh/DQ)/(Duh/Dqh))
- LHS is the MC per unit of the public good
- RHS is the sum of MB across all individuals
Samuelson conditon restated for private and public goods:
Private: MRS between two goods should be the same for all consumers
Public: instead of equating each individuals MRS to the cost P, the sum of all individuals’ MRS must equal P
- here MRS represents the tradeoff each individual is willing to make between the public and private good
- since public goods are shared, each consumer benefits from its provision, so the marginal valuations must be summed.